--- title: "DynareR: Bringing the Power of Dynare to R, R Markdown, and Quarto" author: "Sagiru Mati" date: "`r Sys.Date()`" output: rmarkdown::html_vignette vignette: > %\VignetteIndexEntry{DynareR: Bringing the Power of Dynare to R, R Markdown, and Quarto} %\VignetteEngine{knitr::rmarkdown} %\VignetteEncoding{UTF-8} --- ```{r setup, include = FALSE} knitr::opts_chunk$set( collapse = TRUE, comment = "#>", eval=F, echo = T ) library(magrittr) library(DynareR) ``` # About DynareR DynareR is an R package that can run `Dynare` program from R Markdown. # Requirements Users need the following in order to knit this document: 1. Dynare 4.6.1 or above 1. Octave 5.2.0 or above 1. Dynare is installed in the standard location as follows: * `/usr/lib/dynare/matlab` for `Linux` * `/usr/lib/dynare/matlab` for `macOS` * `c:/dynare/x.y/matlab` for `Windows`, where `x.y` is `Dynare` version number. If `dynare` and `Octave` are installed in standard location, `DynareR` package will take care of the configurations, which include adding `matlab` directory to path, using the latest installed `dynare` and so on. Otherwise, users have to specify the `matlab` folder using `add_path` function, set the `Octave` path using the `set_octave_path` function, or set `dynare` version using the `set_dynare_version` function. # Installation DynareR can be installed using the following commands in R. ```{r installation,eval=FALSE} install.packages("DynareR") OR devtools::install_github('sagirumati/DynareR') ``` # Usage Please load the DynareR package as follows: ```` ```{r DynareR} `r ''` library(DynareR) ``` ```` Then create a chunk for `dynare` (adopted from Dynare example file `bkk`) as shown below: ````` ```{dynare bkk,eval=T} `r ''` /* * This file implements the multi-country RBC model with time to build, * described in Backus, Kehoe and Kydland (1992): "International Real Business * Cycles", Journal of Political Economy, 100(4), 745-775. * * The notation for the variable names are the same in this file than in the paper. * However the timing convention is different: we had to taken into account the * fact that in Dynare, if a variable is denoted at the current period, then * this variable must be also decided at the current period. * Concretely, here are the differences between the paper and the model file: * - z_t in the model file is equal to z_{t+1} in the paper * - k_t in the model file is equal to k_{t+J} in the paper * - s_t in the model file is equal to s_{J,t}=s_{J-1,t+1}=...=s_{1,t+J-1} in the paper * * The macroprocessor is used in this file to create a loop over countries. * Only two countries are used here (as in the paper), but it is easy to add * new countries in the corresponding macro-variable and completing the * calibration. * * The calibration is the same than in the paper. The results in terms of * moments of variables are very close to that of the paper (but not equal * since the authors a different solution method). * * This implementation was written by Sebastien Villemot. Please note that the * following copyright notice only applies to this Dynare implementation of the * model. */ /* * Copyright (C) 2010 Dynare Team * * This file is part of Dynare. * * Dynare is free software: you can redistribute it and/or modify * it under the terms of the GNU General Public License as published by * the Free Software Foundation, either version 3 of the License, or * (at your option) any later version. * * Dynare is distributed in the hope that it will be useful, * but WITHOUT ANY WARRANTY; without even the implied warranty of * MERCHANTABILITY or FITNESS FOR A PARTICULAR PURPOSE. See the * GNU General Public License for more details. * * You should have received a copy of the GNU General Public License * along with Dynare. If not, see . */ @#define countries = [ "H", "F" ] @#define J = 4 @#for co in countries var C_@{co} L_@{co} N_@{co} A_@{co} K_@{co} Z_@{co} X_@{co} LAMBDA_@{co} S_@{co} NX_@{co} Y_@{co}; varexo E_@{co}; parameters beta_@{co} alpha_@{co} eta_@{co} mu_@{co} gamma_@{co} theta_@{co} nu_@{co} sigma_@{co} delta_@{co} phi_@{co} psi_@{co} rho_@{co}_@{co}; @#endfor // Lagrange multiplier of aggregate constraint var LGM; parameters rho_@{countries[1]}_@{countries[2]} rho_@{countries[2]}_@{countries[1]}; model; @#for co in countries Y_@{co} = ((LAMBDA_@{co}*K_@{co}(-@{J})^theta_@{co}*N_@{co}^(1-theta_@{co}))^(-nu_@{co}) + sigma_@{co}*Z_@{co}(-1)^(-nu_@{co}))^(-1/nu_@{co}); K_@{co} = (1-delta_@{co})*K_@{co}(-1) + S_@{co}; X_@{co} = @# for lag in (-J+1):0 + phi_@{co}*S_@{co}(@{lag}) @# endfor ; A_@{co} = (1-eta_@{co})*A_@{co}(-1) + N_@{co}; L_@{co} = 1 - alpha_@{co}*N_@{co} - (1-alpha_@{co})*eta_@{co}*A_@{co}(-1); // Utility multiplied by gamma # U_@{co} = (C_@{co}^mu_@{co}*L_@{co}^(1-mu_@{co}))^gamma_@{co}; // FOC with respect to consumption psi_@{co}*mu_@{co}/C_@{co}*U_@{co} = LGM; // FOC with respect to labor // NOTE: this condition is only valid for alpha = 1 psi_@{co}*(1-mu_@{co})/L_@{co}*U_@{co}*(-alpha_@{co}) = - LGM * (1-theta_@{co})/N_@{co}*(LAMBDA_@{co}*K_@{co}(-@{J})^theta_@{co}*N_@{co}^(1-theta_@{co}))^(-nu_@{co})*Y_@{co}^(1+nu_@{co}); // FOC with respect to capital @# for lag in 0:(J-1) +beta_@{co}^@{lag}*LGM(+@{lag})*phi_@{co} @# endfor @# for lag in 1:J -beta_@{co}^@{lag}*LGM(+@{lag})*phi_@{co}*(1-delta_@{co}) @# endfor = beta_@{co}^@{J}*LGM(+@{J})*theta_@{co}/K_@{co}*(LAMBDA_@{co}(+@{J})*K_@{co}^theta_@{co}*N_@{co}(+@{J})^(1-theta_@{co}))^(-nu_@{co})*Y_@{co}(+@{J})^(1+nu_@{co}); // FOC with respect to stock of inventories LGM=beta_@{co}*LGM(+1)*(1+sigma_@{co}*Z_@{co}^(-nu_@{co}-1)*Y_@{co}(+1)^(1+nu_@{co})); // Shock process @# if co == countries[1] @# define alt_co = countries[2] @# else @# define alt_co = countries[1] @# endif (LAMBDA_@{co}-1) = rho_@{co}_@{co}*(LAMBDA_@{co}(-1)-1) + rho_@{co}_@{alt_co}*(LAMBDA_@{alt_co}(-1)-1) + E_@{co}; NX_@{co} = (Y_@{co} - (C_@{co} + X_@{co} + Z_@{co} - Z_@{co}(-1)))/Y_@{co}; @#endfor // World ressource constraint @#for co in countries +C_@{co} + X_@{co} + Z_@{co} - Z_@{co}(-1) @#endfor = @#for co in countries +Y_@{co} @#endfor ; end; @#for co in countries beta_@{co} = 0.99; mu_@{co} = 0.34; gamma_@{co} = -1.0; alpha_@{co} = 1; eta_@{co} = 0.5; // Irrelevant when alpha=1 theta_@{co} = 0.36; nu_@{co} = 3; sigma_@{co} = 0.01; delta_@{co} = 0.025; phi_@{co} = 1/@{J}; psi_@{co} = 0.5; @#endfor rho_H_H = 0.906; rho_F_F = 0.906; rho_H_F = 0.088; rho_F_H = 0.088; initval; @#for co in countries LAMBDA_@{co} = 1; NX_@{co} = 0; Z_@{co} = 1; A_@{co} = 1; L_@{co} = 0.5; N_@{co} = 0.5; Y_@{co} = 1; K_@{co} = 1; C_@{co} = 1; S_@{co} = 1; X_@{co} = 1; E_@{co} = 0; @#endfor LGM = 1; end; shocks; var E_H; stderr 0.00852; var E_F; stderr 0.00852; corr E_H, E_F = 0.258; end; steady; check; stoch_simul(order=1, hp_filter=1600); ``` ````` ```{dynare bkk,echo=F} /* * This file implements the multi-country RBC model with time to build, * described in Backus, Kehoe and Kydland (1992): "International Real Business * Cycles", Journal of Political Economy, 100(4), 745-775. * * The notation for the variable names are the same in this file than in the paper. * However the timing convention is different: we had to taken into account the * fact that in Dynare, if a variable is denoted at the current period, then * this variable must be also decided at the current period. * Concretely, here are the differences between the paper and the model file: * - z_t in the model file is equal to z_{t+1} in the paper * - k_t in the model file is equal to k_{t+J} in the paper * - s_t in the model file is equal to s_{J,t}=s_{J-1,t+1}=...=s_{1,t+J-1} in the paper * * The macroprocessor is used in this file to create a loop over countries. * Only two countries are used here (as in the paper), but it is easy to add * new countries in the corresponding macro-variable and completing the * calibration. * * The calibration is the same than in the paper. The results in terms of * moments of variables are very close to that of the paper (but not equal * since the authors a different solution method). * * This implementation was written by Sebastien Villemot. Please note that the * following copyright notice only applies to this Dynare implementation of the * model. */ /* * Copyright (C) 2010 Dynare Team * * This file is part of Dynare. * * Dynare is free software: you can redistribute it and/or modify * it under the terms of the GNU General Public License as published by * the Free Software Foundation, either version 3 of the License, or * (at your option) any later version. * * Dynare is distributed in the hope that it will be useful, * but WITHOUT ANY WARRANTY; without even the implied warranty of * MERCHANTABILITY or FITNESS FOR A PARTICULAR PURPOSE. See the * GNU General Public License for more details. * * You should have received a copy of the GNU General Public License * along with Dynare. If not, see . */ @#define countries = [ "H", "F" ] @#define J = 4 @#for co in countries var C_@{co} L_@{co} N_@{co} A_@{co} K_@{co} Z_@{co} X_@{co} LAMBDA_@{co} S_@{co} NX_@{co} Y_@{co}; varexo E_@{co}; parameters beta_@{co} alpha_@{co} eta_@{co} mu_@{co} gamma_@{co} theta_@{co} nu_@{co} sigma_@{co} delta_@{co} phi_@{co} psi_@{co} rho_@{co}_@{co}; @#endfor // Lagrange multiplier of aggregate constraint var LGM; parameters rho_@{countries[1]}_@{countries[2]} rho_@{countries[2]}_@{countries[1]}; model; @#for co in countries Y_@{co} = ((LAMBDA_@{co}*K_@{co}(-@{J})^theta_@{co}*N_@{co}^(1-theta_@{co}))^(-nu_@{co}) + sigma_@{co}*Z_@{co}(-1)^(-nu_@{co}))^(-1/nu_@{co}); K_@{co} = (1-delta_@{co})*K_@{co}(-1) + S_@{co}; X_@{co} = @# for lag in (-J+1):0 + phi_@{co}*S_@{co}(@{lag}) @# endfor ; A_@{co} = (1-eta_@{co})*A_@{co}(-1) + N_@{co}; L_@{co} = 1 - alpha_@{co}*N_@{co} - (1-alpha_@{co})*eta_@{co}*A_@{co}(-1); // Utility multiplied by gamma # U_@{co} = (C_@{co}^mu_@{co}*L_@{co}^(1-mu_@{co}))^gamma_@{co}; // FOC with respect to consumption psi_@{co}*mu_@{co}/C_@{co}*U_@{co} = LGM; // FOC with respect to labor // NOTE: this condition is only valid for alpha = 1 psi_@{co}*(1-mu_@{co})/L_@{co}*U_@{co}*(-alpha_@{co}) = - LGM * (1-theta_@{co})/N_@{co}*(LAMBDA_@{co}*K_@{co}(-@{J})^theta_@{co}*N_@{co}^(1-theta_@{co}))^(-nu_@{co})*Y_@{co}^(1+nu_@{co}); // FOC with respect to capital @# for lag in 0:(J-1) +beta_@{co}^@{lag}*LGM(+@{lag})*phi_@{co} @# endfor @# for lag in 1:J -beta_@{co}^@{lag}*LGM(+@{lag})*phi_@{co}*(1-delta_@{co}) @# endfor = beta_@{co}^@{J}*LGM(+@{J})*theta_@{co}/K_@{co}*(LAMBDA_@{co}(+@{J})*K_@{co}^theta_@{co}*N_@{co}(+@{J})^(1-theta_@{co}))^(-nu_@{co})*Y_@{co}(+@{J})^(1+nu_@{co}); // FOC with respect to stock of inventories LGM=beta_@{co}*LGM(+1)*(1+sigma_@{co}*Z_@{co}^(-nu_@{co}-1)*Y_@{co}(+1)^(1+nu_@{co})); // Shock process @# if co == countries[1] @# define alt_co = countries[2] @# else @# define alt_co = countries[1] @# endif (LAMBDA_@{co}-1) = rho_@{co}_@{co}*(LAMBDA_@{co}(-1)-1) + rho_@{co}_@{alt_co}*(LAMBDA_@{alt_co}(-1)-1) + E_@{co}; NX_@{co} = (Y_@{co} - (C_@{co} + X_@{co} + Z_@{co} - Z_@{co}(-1)))/Y_@{co}; @#endfor // World ressource constraint @#for co in countries +C_@{co} + X_@{co} + Z_@{co} - Z_@{co}(-1) @#endfor = @#for co in countries +Y_@{co} @#endfor ; end; @#for co in countries beta_@{co} = 0.99; mu_@{co} = 0.34; gamma_@{co} = -1.0; alpha_@{co} = 1; eta_@{co} = 0.5; // Irrelevant when alpha=1 theta_@{co} = 0.36; nu_@{co} = 3; sigma_@{co} = 0.01; delta_@{co} = 0.025; phi_@{co} = 1/@{J}; psi_@{co} = 0.5; @#endfor rho_H_H = 0.906; rho_F_F = 0.906; rho_H_F = 0.088; rho_F_H = 0.088; initval; @#for co in countries LAMBDA_@{co} = 1; NX_@{co} = 0; Z_@{co} = 1; A_@{co} = 1; L_@{co} = 0.5; N_@{co} = 0.5; Y_@{co} = 1; K_@{co} = 1; C_@{co} = 1; S_@{co} = 1; X_@{co} = 1; E_@{co} = 0; @#endfor LGM = 1; end; shocks; var E_H; stderr 0.00852; var E_F; stderr 0.00852; corr E_H, E_F = 0.258; end; steady; check; stoch_simul(order=1, hp_filter=1600,graph_format = (pdf)); ``` The above chunk creates a Dynare program with the chunk’s content, then automatically run Dynare, which will save Dynare outputs in the current directory. Please note that DynareR uses the chunk name as the model name. So, the outpus of Dynare are saved in a folder with its respective chunk name. Thus a new folder `bkk/` will be created in your current working directory. By default, `dynare` chunk imports log output as a list of dataframes, which can be accessed via `dynare$modelName`. Therefore to access the outputs of the `bkk` model produced by the `dynare` chunk, use `dynare$bkk`. Use inline code `` `r knitr::inline_expr('dynare$bkk$moments[2,3]', 'md')` `` to access the value of second row and third column of the `moments`, which is `r dynare$bkk$moments[2,3]`. # Plotting the IRF The Impulse Response Function (IRF) is saved by default in `bkk/bkk/graphs/` folder with the IRF's name `bkk_IRF_E_H2.pdf`, where `bkk` is the Dynare model's name. Therefore, you need to add `stoch_simul(graph_format = (pdf))` to change the default saving behaviour of `Dynare` from `eps` to `pdf`. # DynareR functions for base R The DynareR package is also designed to work with base R. The following functions show how to work with DynareR outside the R Markdown or Quarto documents. ## The include_IRF function Use this function to embed the graphs Impulse Response Function (IRF) in R Markdown or Quarto document. The Impulse Response Function (IRF) of the `bkk` model can be fetched using the following R chunk. Note that only the last part of the IRF's name (`E_H2`) is needed, that is `bkk_IRF_` is excluded. Also note that `out.extra='trim={0cm 7cm 0cm 7cm},clip'` is used to trim the white space above and below the IRF. ```` ```{r IRF,out.extra='trim={0cm 7cm 0cm 7cm},clip',fig.cap="Another of figure generated from Dynare software"} `r ''` include_IRF("bkk","E_H2") # Alternatively, use the path argument ``` ```` ```{r IRF,out.extra='trim={0cm 7cm 0cm 7cm},clip',fig.cap="Another of figure generated from Dynare software"} include_IRF(model="bkk",IRF = "E_H2") # Alternatively, use the path argument include_IRF(path="bkk/bkk/graphs/bkk_IRF_E_H2.pdf") ``` However, Dynare figure can only be dynamically included if the output format is pdf as Dynare produces pdf and eps graphs only. ## The write_dyn function This function writes a new `dyn` file. Use `write_dyn(code="code",model="someModel")` if you want the `Dynare` file to live in the current working directory. Use `write_dyn(code="code",model="path/to/someDirectory/someModel")` if you want the Dynare file to live in the path different from the current working directory. ```{r exampleDyn} dynareCodes='var y, c, k, a, h, b; varexo e, u; parameters beta, rho, alpha, delta, theta, psi, tau; alpha = 0.36; rho = 0.95; tau = 0.025; beta = 0.99; delta = 0.025; psi = 0; theta = 2.95; phi = 0.1; model; c*theta*h^(1+psi)=(1-alpha)*y; k = beta*(((exp(b)*c)/(exp(b(+1))*c(+1))) *(exp(b(+1))*alpha*y(+1)+(1-delta)*k)); y = exp(a)*(k(-1)^alpha)*(h^(1-alpha)); k = exp(b)*(y-c)+(1-delta)*k(-1); a = rho*a(-1)+tau*b(-1) + e; b = tau*a(-1)+rho*b(-1) + u; end; initval; y = 1.08068253095672; c = 0.80359242014163; h = 0.29175631001732; k = 11.08360443260358; a = 0; b = 0; e = 0; u = 0; end; shocks; var e; stderr 0.009; var u; stderr 0.009; var e, u = phi*0.009*0.009; end; stoch_simul;' write_dyn(code=dynareCodes, model="example1") write_dyn(code=dynareCodes,model="DynareR/write_dyn/example1") ``` ## The write_mod function This function writes a new `mod` file. Use `write_mod(code="code",model="someModel")` if you want the `Dynare` file to live in the current working directory. Use `write_mod(code="code",model="path/to/someDirectory/someModel")` if you want the Dynare file to live in the path different from the current working directory. ```{r examplemod} DynareCodes='var y, c, k, a, h, b; varexo e, u; parameters beta, rho, alpha, delta, theta, psi, tau; alpha = 0.36; rho = 0.95; tau = 0.025; beta = 0.99; delta = 0.025; psi = 0; theta = 2.95; phi = 0.1; model; c*theta*h^(1+psi)=(1-alpha)*y; k = beta*(((exp(b)*c)/(exp(b(+1))*c(+1))) *(exp(b(+1))*alpha*y(+1)+(1-delta)*k)); y = exp(a)*(k(-1)^alpha)*(h^(1-alpha)); k = exp(b)*(y-c)+(1-delta)*k(-1); a = rho*a(-1)+tau*b(-1) + e; b = tau*a(-1)+rho*b(-1) + u; end; initval; y = 1.08068253095672; c = 0.80359242014163; h = 0.29175631001732; k = 11.08360443260358; a = 0; b = 0; e = 0; u = 0; end; shocks; var e; stderr 0.009; var u; stderr 0.009; var e, u = phi*0.009*0.009; end; stoch_simul;' write_mod(model="example1",code=dynareCodes) write_mod(code=dynareCodes,model="DynareR/write_mod/example1") ``` ## The run_dynare function Create and run Dynare `mod` file Use this function to create and run Dynare mod file. Use `run_dynare(code="code",model="someModel")` if you want the Dynare files to live in the current working directory. Use `run_dynare(code="code",model="path/to/someDirectory/someModel")` if you want the Dynare files to live in the path different from the current working directory. Use `import_log=T` argument to return the `dynare` log file as list of dataframes in an environment `dynare`, which can be accessed via `dynare$modelName`. ```{r exampleRunDynare} DynareCodes='var y, c, k, a, h, b; varexo e, u; parameters beta, rho, alpha, delta, theta, psi, tau; alpha = 0.36; rho = 0.95; tau = 0.025; beta = 0.99; delta = 0.025; psi = 0; theta = 2.95; phi = 0.1; model; c*theta*h^(1+psi)=(1-alpha)*y; k = beta*(((exp(b)*c)/(exp(b(+1))*c(+1))) *(exp(b(+1))*alpha*y(+1)+(1-delta)*k)); y = exp(a)*(k(-1)^alpha)*(h^(1-alpha)); k = exp(b)*(y-c)+(1-delta)*k(-1); a = rho*a(-1)+tau*b(-1) + e; b = tau*a(-1)+rho*b(-1) + u; end; initval; y = 1.08068253095672; c = 0.80359242014163; h = 0.29175631001732; k = 11.08360443260358; a = 0; b = 0; e = 0; u = 0; end; shocks; var e; stderr 0.009; var u; stderr 0.009; var e, u = phi*0.009*0.009; end; stoch_simul;' run_dynare(code=DynareCodes,model="example1",import_log = T) run_dynare(code=DynareCodes,model="DynareR/run_dynare/example1") ``` ## The run_models function Run multiple existing `mod` or `dyn` files. Use this function to execute multiple existing Dynare files. Use `run_models(model="someModel")` if the Dynare files live in the current working directory. Use `run_models(model="path/to/someDirectory/someModel")` if the Dynare files live in the path different from the current working directory. Use `run_models()` to exectute all the `dynare` models in the current working directory. Use `run_models("path/to/someDirectory*)` to run all the `dynare` models in `path/to/someDirectory`. Where `agtrend.mod`, `bkk.mod` and `example1.mod` are the Dynare model files (with `mod` or `dyn` extension), which live in the current working directory. ```{r exampleRunModels} demo(agtrend) demo(bkk) demo(example1) # Provide the list of the `Dynare` files in a vector # Ensure that "agtrend.mod", "bkk.mod" and "example1.mod" # live in the current working directory # Copy the dynare files to the current working directory lapply(c("agtrend","bkk","example1"),\(x) file.copy(paste0(x,"/",x,".mod"),".")) run_models(c("agtrend","bkk","example1")) # Run the models in the vector. ``` To run all `Dynare` models that live in the current working directory, use the following: ```{r runAllDynare} run_models() # Run all models in Current Working Directory. ``` To run all `Dynare` models that live in particular path (for example 'DynareR/run_dynare/' folder), use the following: ```{r runAllDynare1} # Copy the dynare files to the 'DynareR/run_dynare' directory lapply(c("agtrend","bkk","example1"),\(x) file.copy(paste0(x,".mod"),"DynareR/run_dynare")) run_models(model = 'DynareR/run_dynare*') # notice the * at the end ``` # import_log function This function returns the `dynare` log output as a list of dataframes, which include `summary`, `shocks`, `policy`, `moments`, `decomposition`, `correlation` and `autocorrelation`. The list is accessible via `dynare$modelName`. if the model name is `bkk`, the policy variables can be obtained via `dynare$bkk$policy` as a dataframe. ```{r importLog} import_log(model="bkk") import_log(path="bkk/bkk.log") knitr::kable(dynare$bkk$autocorrelation) # %>% kableExtra::kable_styling(latex_options = c("basic","hold_position","scale_down")) %>% # kableExtra::footnote(general="Some footnote with equation $\\alpha x^2+\\beta x+c=0$", general_title = "*",footnote_as_chunk=T,threeparttable=T,escape=F) %>% # kableExtra::row_spec(0,bold=T) ``` # set_dynare_version function On Windows, you can set the version of dynare you want to use. By default, `DynareR` package does this for you if the dynare version ranges from 4.6.1 to 9.9. However, if you are using the development version of `dynare`, for example version `6-unstable-2022-04-03-0800-700a0e3a`, you can override the default as follows ```{r dynareVersion,eval=F} set_dynare_version("6-unstable-2022-04-03-0800-700a0e3a") ``` # set_octave_path function You can use this function if `Octave` is not installed in the standard location ```{r OctavePath} set_octave_path('C:/Program Files/GNU Octave/Octave-6.4.0/mingw64/bin/octave20.exe') ``` # add_path function This function is a wrapper of `addpath` in `Octave`. If `dynare` is not installed in the standard location, use this function to add the `matlab` subdirectory. By default, `DynareR` does this for if `dynare` is installed in the standard location. ```{r addPath,eval=FALSE} add_path('/usr/lib/dynare/matlab')# Default for Linux add_path('c:/dynare/5.1/matlab') # Default for Windows, but 5.1 can change if later version of # `Dynare` is installed. add_path('/usr/lib/dynare/matlab') # Default for macOS ``` # Demo The demo files are included and can be accessed via demo(package="DynareR") ```{r demo} demo(run_dynare) demo(run_models) demo(import_log) ``` # Template Template for R Markdown is created. Go to `file->New File->R Markdown-> From Template->DynareR`. # Similar Packages Similar packages include [EviewsR](https://github.com/sagirumati/EviewsR) (Mati 2022b, 2020b,Mati, Civcir, and Abba 2023), [gretlR](https://github.com/sagirumati/gretlR) (Mati 2020c, 2022c), and [URooTab](https://github.com/sagirumati/URooTab) (Mati 2023b, 2023a) For further details, consult Mati (2020a) and Mati (2022a).



Please download the example files from [Github](https://github.com/sagirumati/DynareR/tree/master/inst/examples/). # References Mati, Sagiru. 2020a. “DynareR: Bringing the Power of Dynare to R, R Markdown, and Quarto.” *CRAN*. . ———. 2020b. *EviewsR: A Seamless Integration of EViews and R*. . ———. 2020c. *gretlR: A Seamless Integration of Gretl and R*. . ———. 2021. “Do as Your Neighbours Do? Assessing the Impact of Lockdown and Reopening on the Active COVID-19 Cases in Nigeria.” *Social Science &Amp; Medicine* 270 (February): 113645. . ———. 2022a. “Package ‘DynareR’.” . ———. 2022b. “Package ‘EviewsR’.” . ———. 2022c. “Package ‘gretlR’.” . ———. 2023a. “Package ‘URooTab’.” . ———. 2023b. *URooTab: Tabular Reporting of EViews Unit Root Tests*. . Mati, Sagiru, Irfan Civcir, and S. I. Abba. 2023. “EviewsR: An r Package for Dynamic and Reproducible Research Using EViews, r, r Markdown and Quarto.” *The R Journal* 15 (2): 169–205. . Mati, Sagiru, Irfan Civcir, and Hüseyin Ozdeser. 2019. “ECOWAS COMMON CURRENCY: HOW PREPARED ARE ITS MEMBERS?” *Investigación Económica* 78 (308): 89. . Mati, Sagiru, Irfan Civcir, and Hüseyin Özdeşer. 2023. “ECOWAS Common Currency, a Mirage or Possibility?” *Panoeconomicus* 70 (2): 239–60. . Mati, Sagiru, Magdalena Radulescu, Najia Saqib, Ahmed Samour, Goran Yousif Ismael, and Nazifi Aliyu. 2023. “Incorporating Russo-Ukrainian War in Brent Crude Oil Price Forecasting: A Comparative Analysis of ARIMA, TARMA and ENNReg Models.” *Heliyon* 9 (11): e21439. .